关键词不能为空

当前您在: 主页 > 英语 >

克鲁格曼 国际经济学第10版 英文答案 国际金融部分krugman_intlecon10_im_14_GE

作者:高考题库网
来源:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao
2021-03-03 08:23
tags:

-

2021年3月3日发(作者:制订)


Chapter 14 (3)



Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market:


An Asset Approach


?



Chapter Organization


Exchange Rates and International Transactions




Domestic and Foreign Prices




Exchange Rates and Relative Prices


The Foreign Exchange Market




The Actors



Box: Exchange Rates, Auto Prices, and Currency Wars




Characteristics of the Market




Spot Rates and Forward Rates




Foreign Exchange Swaps




Futures and Options


The Demand for Foreign Currency Assets




Assets and Asset Returns




Box: Nondeliverable Forward Exchange Trading in Asia





Risk and Liquidity




Interest Rates




Exchange Rates and Asset Returns




A Simple Rule




Return, Risk, and Liquidity in the Foreign Exchange Market


Equilibrium in the Foreign Exchange Market




Interest Parity: The Basic Equilibrium Condition




How Changes in the Current Exchange Rate Affect Expected Returns




The Equilibrium Exchange Rate


Interest Rates, Expectations, and Equilibrium




The Effect of Changing Interest Rates on the Current Exchange Rate




The Effect of Changing Expectations on the Current Exchange Rate




Case Study: What Explains the Carry Trade?



Summary


APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 14 (3): Forward Exchange Rates and Covered Interest Parity


? 2015 Pearson Education Limited



?



Chapter Overview


The purpose of this chapter is to show the importance of the exchange rate in translating foreign prices


into domestic values as well as to begin the presentation of exchange rate determination. Central to the


treatment of exchange rate determination is the insight that exchange rates are determined in the same way


a


s other asset prices. The chapter begins by describing how the relative prices of different countries’ goods


are affected by exchange rate changes. This discussion illustrates the central importance of exchange rates


for cross-border economic linkages. The determination of the level of the exchange rate is modeled in


the context of the exchange rate’s role as the relative price of foreign and domestic currencies, using the


uncovered interest parity relationship.


The euro is used often in examples. Some students may not be familiar with the currency or aware of


which countries use it; a brief discussion may be warranted. A full treatment of EMU and the theories


surrounding currency unification appears in Chapter 20(9).


The description of the foreign exchange market stresses the involvement of large organizations (commercial


banks, corporations, nonbank financial institutions, and central banks) and the highly integrated nature


of the market. The nature of the foreign exchange market ensures that arbitrage occurs quickly so that


common rates are offered worldwide. A comparison of the trading volume in foreign exchange markets to


that in other markets is useful to underscore how quickly price arbitrage occurs and equilibrium is restored.


Forward foreign exchange trading, foreign exchange futures contracts, and foreign exchange options play


an important part in currency market activity. The use of these financial instruments to eliminate short-run


exchange rate risk is described.


The explanation of exchange rate determination in this chapter emphasizes the modern view that exchange


rates move to equilibrate asset markets. The foreign exchange demand and supply curves that introduce


exchange rate determination in most undergraduate texts are not found here. Instead, there is a discussion


of asset pricing and the determination of expected rates of return on assets denominated in different


currencies.


Students may already be familiar with the distinction between real and nominal returns. The text demonstrates


that nominal returns are sufficient for comparing the attractiveness of different assets. There is a brief


description of the role played by risk and liquidity in asset demand, but these considerations are not


pursued in this chapter. (The role of risk is taken up again in Chapter 18[7].)


Substantial space is devoted to the topic of comparing expected returns on assets denominated in domestic


and foreign currency. The text identifies two parts of the expected return on a foreign currency asset


(measured in domestic currency terms): the interest payment and the change in the value of the foreign


currency relative to the domestic currency over the period in which the asset is held. The expected return


on a foreign asset is calculated as a function of the current exchange rate for given expected values of the


future exchange rate and the foreign interest rate.


The absence of risk and liquidity considerations implies that the expected returns on all assets traded in the


foreign exchange market must be equal. It is thus a short step from calculations of expected returns on foreign


assets to the interest parity condition. The foreign exchange market is shown to be in equilibrium only when


the interest parity condition holds. Thus, for given interest rates and given expectations about future exchange


rates, interest parity determines the current equilibrium exchange rate. The interest parity diagram introduced


here is instrumental in later chapters in which a more general model is presented. Because a command of


this interest parity diagram is an important building block for future work, we recommend drills that


employ this diagram.


The result that a dollar appreciation makes foreign currency assets more attractive may appear counterintuitive


to students



why does a stronger dollar reduce the expected return on dollar assets? The key to explaining


this point is that, under the static expectations and constant interest rates assumptions, a dollar appreciation


today implies a greater future dollar depreciation; so, an American investor can expect to gain not only the


Chapter 14


Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market: An Asset Approach



77


foreign interest payment but also the extra return due to the dollar’s additional future depreciation. The


following diagram illustrates this point. In this diagram, the exchange rate at time


t



?


1 is expected to be


equal to


E


. If the exchange rate at time


t


is also


E


,



then expected depreciation is 0. If, however, the exchange


rate depreciates at time


t


to


E


??


then it must appreciate to reach


E


at time


t



??


1. If the exchange rate appreciates


today to


E


??


then it must depreciate to reach


E


at time


t



??


1. Thus, under static expectations, a depreciation


today implies an expected appreciation and vice versa.




Figure 14(3)-1


This pedagogical tool can be employed to provide some further intuition behind the interest parity


relationship. Suppose that the domestic and foreign interest rates are equal. Interest parity then requires


that the expected depreciation is equal to zero and that the exchange rate today and next period is equal


to


E


. If the domestic interest rate rises, people will want to hold more domestic currency deposits. The


resulting increased demand for domestic currency drives up the price of domestic currency, causing the


exchange rate to appreciate. How long will this continue? The answer is that the appreciation of the


domestic currency continues until the expected depreciation that is a consequence of the domestic


currency’s appreciation today just offsets the interest differential.



The text presents exercises on the effects of changes in interest rates and of changes in expectations of


the future exchange rate. These exercises can help develop students’ intuition. For example, the initial


result of a rise in U.S. interest rates is a higher demand for dollar-denominated assets and thus an increase


in the price of the dollar. This dollar appreciation is large enough that the subsequent expected dollar


depreciation just equalizes the expected return on foreign currency assets (measured in dollar terms) and


the higher dollar interest rate.


The chapter concludes with a case study looking at a situation in which interest rate parity may not hold:


the carry trade. In a carry trade, investors borrow money in low-interest currencies and buy high-interest-


rate currencies, often earning profits over long periods of time. However, this transaction carries an element


of risk as the high- interest-rate currency may experience an abrupt crash in value. The case study discusses


a popular carry trade in which investors borrowed low-interest-rate Japanese yen to purchase high-interest-


rate Australian dollars. Investors earned high returns until 2008, when the Australian dollar abruptly crashed,


losing 40 percent of its value. This was an especially large loss as the crash occurred amidst a financial


crisis in which liquidity was highly valued. Thus, when we factor in this additional risk of the carry trade,


interest rate parity may still hold.


The Appendix describes the covered interest parity relationship and applies it to explain the determination


of forward rates under risk neutrality as well as the high correlation between movements in spot and


forward rates.


? 2015 Pearson Education Limited



?



Answers to Textbook Problems



1.


At an exchange rate of 1.05 $$ per euro, a 5 euro bratwurst costs 1.05$$/euro


?


5 euros


?


$$5.25. Thus,


the bratwurst in Munich is $$1.25 more expensive than the hot dog in Boston. The relative price is


$$5.25/$$4


?


1.31. A bratwurst costs 1.31 hot dogs. If the dollar depreciates to 1.25$$/euro, the bratwurst


now costs 1.25$$/euro


?


5 euros


?


$$6.25, for a relative price of $$6.25/$$4


?


1.56. You have to give up


1.56 hot dogs to buy a bratwurst. Hot dogs have become relatively cheaper than bratwurst after the


depreciation of the dollar.



2.


If it were cheaper to buy Israeli shekels with Swiss francs that were purchased with dollars than to


directly buy shekels with dollars, then people would act upon this arbitrage opportunity. The demand


for Swiss francs from people who hold dollars would rise, causing the Swiss franc to rise in value


against the dollar. The Swiss franc would appreciate against the dollar until the price of a shekel


would be exactly the same whether it was purchased directly with dollars or indirectly through Swiss


francs.



3.


Take for example the exchange rate between the Argentine peso, the US dollar, the euro, and the


British pound. One dollar is worth 5.3015 pesos, while a euro is worth 7.0089 pesos. To rule out


triangular arbitrage, we need to see how many pesos you would get if you first bought euros with


your dollars (at an exchange rate of 0.7564 euros per dollar), then used these euros to buy pesos. In


other words, we need to compute E



= E


EUR/USD


×


E


ARG/EUR


= 0.7564×


7.0089 = 5.3015 pesos


per dollar. This is almost exactly (with rounding) equal to the direct rate of pesos per dollar.


Following the same procedure for the British pound yields a similar result.




We need to say that triangular arbitrage is “approximately” ruled out for several reasons. First,


rounding error means that there may be some small discrepancies between the direct and indirect


exchange rates we calculate. Second, transactions costs on trading currencies will prevent complete


arbitrage from occurring. That said, the massive volume of currencies traded make these transactions


costs relatively small, leading to “near” perfect arbitrage.




4.


A depreciation of Chinese yuan makes the import more expensive. Since the demand for oil is


inelastic, China needs to import oil from the oil exporting countries. This leads to spending more on


oil when the exchange rate falls in value. This can cause the balance of payment to worsen in the


short run. Hence, a depreciation of domestic currency may or may not have a favourable impact on


the balance of payment in the short run.



5.


The dollar rates of return are as follows:


a.


($$250,000


?


$$200,000)/$$200,000


?


0.25.


b.


($$275


?


$$255)/$$255


?


0.08.


c.


There are two parts to this return. One is the loss involved due to the appreciation of the dollar;


the dollar appreciation is ($$1.38


?


$$1.50)/$$1.50


?



?


0.08. The other part of the return is the interest


paid by the London bank on the deposit, 10 percent. (The size of the deposit is immaterial to the


calculation of the rate of return.) In terms of dollars, the realized return on the London deposit


is thus 2 percent per year.

-


-


-


-


-


-


-


-



本文更新与2021-03-03 08:23,由作者提供,不代表本网站立场,转载请注明出处:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao/698302.html

克鲁格曼 国际经济学第10版 英文答案 国际金融部分krugman_intlecon10_im_14_GE的相关文章

克鲁格曼 国际经济学第10版 英文答案 国际金融部分krugman_intlecon10_im_14_GE随机文章