关键词不能为空

当前您在: 主页 > 英语 >

服装商品链中的国际贸易与产业升级【外文翻译】

作者:高考题库网
来源:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao
2021-02-16 13:20
tags:

-

2021年2月16日发(作者:yixi)



外文翻译



原文



International Trade and Industrial Upgrading in the Apparel


Commodity Chain


Material Source:Journal of International Economics,l999,48(1)






















Author:


Gary Geref?



Abstract





This


article uses


a global


commodity chains


perspective to


analyze the social


and


organizational


dimensions


of


international


trade


networks.


In


linking


international trade and industrial upgrading, this article speci?es: the mechanisms by


which


organizational


learning


occurs


in


trade


networks;


typical


trajectories


from


assembly


to


OEM


and


OBM


export


roles;


and


the


organizational


conditions


that


facilitate industrial upgrading moves such as the shift from assembly to full-package


networks. The empirical focus is the apparel industry, with an emphasis on Asia. ?


1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.



Keywords:


Global


commodity


chains;


Industrial


upgrading;


OEM;


OBM;


Apparel


Globalization


has


altered


the


competitive


dynamics


of


nations,


?rms,


and


industries.


This


is


most


clearly


seen


in


changing


patterns


of


international


trade,


where


the


explosive


growth


of


imports


in


developed


countries


indicates


that


the


center of gravity for the production and export of many manufactures has moved to


an


ever


expanding


array


of


newly


industrializing


economies


(NIEs)


in


the


Third


World. This shift is central to the ‘East Asian miracle,’ which refers to the handful


of high-performing Asian economies that have attained lofty per capita growth rates,


relatively


low


income


inequality,


high


educational


attainment,


record


levels


of


domestic


saving


and


investment,


and


booming


exports


from


the


1960s


to


the


mid-1990s


(World


Bank,


1993).


Regardless


of


whether


the


growth


is


due


to


productivity gains or to capital accumulation (Krugman, 1994; Young, 1994, 1995),


their economic achievement is largely attributed to the adoption of export- oriented


industrialization as the region’s main development strategy.



This view of international trade as the fulcrum for sustained economic growth



in East Asia, while unassailable in its macroeconomic basics, nonetheless leaves a


number


of


critical


questions


unanswered


in


terms


of


the


microinstitutional


foundations


supporting


East


Asian


development.


Why


were


Japan


and


the


East


Asian


NIEs


(South


Korea,


Taiwan,


Hong


Kong


and


Singapore)


so


successful


in


exporting


to


distant


Western


markets,


given


the


formidable


spatial


and


cultural


distances that had to be bridged? How were these East Asian nations able to sustain


their high rates of export-oriented growth over three to four decades, in the face of a


variety of adverse economic factors such as oil price hikes, rising wage rates, labor


shortages, currency appreciations, a global recession, and spreading protectionism in


their major export markets? Under what conditions can trade-based growth become


a


vehicle


for


genuine


industrial


upgrading,


given


the


frequent


criticisms


made


of


low-wage,


low-skill,


assembly-oriented


export


ac


tivities?


Do


Asia’s


accomplishments


in


trade-


led


industrialization


contain


signi?


cant


lessons


for


other


regions of the world?



This


article


will


address


these


questions


using


a


global


commodity


chains


framework. A commodity chain refers to the whole range of activities involved in


the


design,


production,


and


marketing


of


a


product.


A


critical


distinction


in


this


approach is between buyer-driven and producer-driven commodity chains. Japan in


the 1950s and 1960s, the East Asian NIEs during the 1970s and 1980s, and China in


the


1990s


became


world-class


exporters


primarily


by


mastering


the


dynamics


of


buyer-driven


commodity


chains,


which


supply


a


wide


range


of


labor- intensive


consumer products such as apparel, footwear, toys, and sporting goods. The key to


success in East Asia’s buyer


-driven chains was to move from the mere assembly of


imported


inputs


(traditionally


associated


with


export-processing


zones)


to


a


more


domestically


integrated


and


higher


value- added


form


of


exporting


known


alternatively


as


full-package


supply


or


OEM


(original


equipment


manufacturing)


production.


Subsequently,


Japan


and


some


?rms


in


the


Ea


st


Asian


NIEs


pushed


beyond


the


OEM


export


role


to


original


brand


name


manufacturing


(OBM)


by


joining


their


production


expertise


with


the


design


and


sale


of


their


own


branded


merchandise in domestic and overseas markets.



From


a


global


commodity


chains


per


spective,


East


Asia’s


transition


from


assembly to full- package supply derives in large measure from its ability to establish


close linkages with a diverse array of lead ?rms in buyer


-


driven chains. Lead ?rms


are


the


primary


sources


of


material


inputs,


technology


transfer,


and


knowledge


in


these


organizational


networks.


In


the


apparel


commodity


chain,


different


types


of



lead ?rms use different networks and source in different parts of



1


Throughout this article, OEM production will be used as a synonymous term


for


relational


contracting,


speci?cation


contracting,


and


full


-package


supply.


the


world.


Retailers


and


marketers


tend


to


rely


on


full-package


sourcing


networks,


in


which


they


buy


ready-made


apparel


primarily


from


Asia,


where


manufacturers


in


places like Hong Kong, Taiwan and South Korea have historically specialized in this


kind


of


production.


As


wage


levels


in


those


countries


have


gone


up,


East


Asian


manufacturers have tended to develop multilayered global sourcing networks where


low-wage assembly can be done in other parts of Asia, Africa and Latin America,


while


the


NIE


manufacturers


play


a


critical


coordinating


role


in


the


full- package


production


process.


Branded


manufacturers,


by


contrast,


tend


to


create


production


networks


that


focus


on


apparel


assembly


using


imported


inputs.


Whereas


full-package


sourcing


networks


are


generally


global,


production


networks


established by branded manufacturers are predominantly regional. US manufacturers


go to Mexico and the Caribbean Basin, European Union ?rms look


to North Africa


and Eastern Europe, and Japan and the East Asian NIEs look to lower-wage regions


within Asia.



Industrial upgrading, from this perspective, involves organizational learning to


improve the position of ?rms or nations in international trade networks (Geref? and


Tam,


1998).


Participation


in


global


commodity


chains


is


a


necessary


step


for


industrial


upgrading


because


it


puts


?rms


and


economies


on


potentially


dynamic


learning curves. There are many obstacles, however, to moving up these chains from


labor-intensive activities like export- oriented assembly, to more integrated forms of


manufacturing


like


OEM


and


OBM


production,


to


the


most


pro?table


and/or


skill-intensive economic activities such as breakthrough innovations in


new


goods


and services


, design, marketing, and ?nance. Therefore, we need to address not only


why industrial upgrading occurs in global commodity chains, but also how it occurs.


A


commodity


chains


framework


that


attempts


to


link


international


trade


and


industrial upgrading must specify: the mechanisms by which organizational learning


occurs


in


trade


networks;


typical


trajectories


among


export


roles;


and


the


organizational conditions that facilitate industrial upgrading moves such as the shift


from assembly to full-package networks.



The economic theory of industrial upgrading is that as capital (both human and


physical)


becomes


more


abundant


relative


to


labor


and


the


endowments


of


other


countries,


nations


develop


comparative


advantages


in


capital-and


skill-intensive



industries (Porter, 1990). This article will show, however, that upgrading does not


occur to a random set of capital-or skill-intensive industries or activities, but rather


to


products


that


are


organizationally


related


through


the


lead


?rms


in


global


commodity chains.



The microfoundations of this upgrading pattern involve both forward (market-


ing) and backward (sourcing) linkages from production, and the kind of learning that


occurs across these segments. With regard to marketing, countries that are upgrading


within c


ommodity chains have already identi?ed the buyers for their products within


the chains. The implication is that marketing outside the chain is more dif?cult due


to


search costs


and the fact


that


foreign buyers provide access to


information that


assists local suppliers in their export and marketing efforts (Rhee et al., 1984). For


sourcing


linkages,


both


technological


and


tacit


knowledge


exists


about


how


and


where to establish new export capacity for ?nished products. There is a clear pattern


of


organizational


succession


in


buyer-driven


chains,


however,


whereby


foreign


buyers


that


occupy


distinct


positions


(or


price


points)


in


the


retail


sectors


of


their


home markets source from each of the major Asian exporting nations in distinctive


cycles


or


sequences


(Ger


ef?,


1994).


This


succession


mechanism


drives


the


geographical


expansion


of


global


sourcing


networks,


as


buyers


for


less


expensive


goods are pushed into lower-cost production sites, and it is also crucial for industrial


upgrading


because


the


higher


price


po


ints


of


fashionable


retailers


re?ect


more


complicated products and differentiated styles.



Our


empirical


focus


in


this


article


will


be


the


apparel


industry,


with


an


emphasis on Asia. This selection is justi?ed on multiple grounds. Apparel is one of


the oldest and largest export industries in the world. Most nations produce for the


international textile and apparel market (Dickerson, 1995, p. 6), making this one of


the most global of all industries. Apparel is the typical ‘starter’ industry for countries


engaged in


export-oriented industrialization, and it played the leading


role in


East


Asia’s


early


export


growth.


The


apparel


industry


is


a


prototypical


buyer


-driven


commodity chain because it generates a highly aggressive pattern of global sourcing


through


a


variety


of


organizational


channels,


including


giant


cost-driven


discount


chains


(Wal-Mart,


Kmart,


or


Target),


upscale


branded


marketers


(Liz


Claiborne,


Tommy


Hil?ger,


Nautica),


apparel


specialty


stores


(The


Limited,


The


Gap),


and


burgeoning


private


label


programs


among


mass


merchandise


retailers


(JC


Penney,


Sears). Finally, apparel embodies two contrasting production systems characteristic


of buyer-driven chains: the assembly and the OEM models. Whereas the assembly

-


-


-


-


-


-


-


-



本文更新与2021-02-16 13:20,由作者提供,不代表本网站立场,转载请注明出处:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao/658811.html

服装商品链中的国际贸易与产业升级【外文翻译】的相关文章

服装商品链中的国际贸易与产业升级【外文翻译】随机文章