关键词不能为空

当前您在: 主页 > 英语 >

财务风险管理是一个增值活动吗文献翻译

作者:高考题库网
来源:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao
2021-02-10 01:24
tags:

-

2021年2月10日发(作者:alacrity)


原文:



Financial risk management: is it a value-adding activity




Financial risk management is a process to deal with the uncertainties


resulting from financial markers. It involves assessing the financial risks


facing an organization and developing management strategies consistent with


internal priorities and policies. Addressing financial risks proactively may


provide an organization with a competitive advantage. It also ensures that


management, operational staff, stakeholders, and the board of directors are


in agreement on key issues of risk.



Considering whether financial risk management is value-adding. Although


risk


management


can


reduce


total


risk,


this


may


not


affect


the cost


of


capital


or firm value. Well-diversified investors have already eliminated all of the


specific


risk,


and


risk-management


may


be


seen


as


a


zero


NPV


activity


at


best,


and at worst, a value- reducing activity. However, there is a role for risk


management.


Reduction


of


total


risk


may


reduce


the


expected


costs


of


financial


distress,


this increases


firm value. Present a


method of investment


appraisal


that takes account of total risk through expected financial distress costs.


Such


a


method


can


result


in


three


possible


decisions


relating


to


a


new


project;


reject the project invest in the project; and risk-manage; or invest in the


project but do not risk-manage. Finally, presents worked examples.



When considering a firm’s financial risk management activities, we may


ask two questions; why do firms engage in such activities, and how do they do


it? How firms engage in risk-management has been extensively considered.



Methods


typically


involve


combining


financial


instruments


such


as


shares,


bonds,


options and futures, in order to obtain a desired payoff profile (see Smith


and Smithson (1998) for an excellent analysis).



In


this


paper,


we


consider


the


more


controversial


question;


why


bother


with


financial risk-management? Is financial risk-management value adding?



Shapiro


and


Titman


(1998)


consider


this


question


of


whether


risk


management


is


desirable.


A


firm’s


total


risk


consists


of


two


elements;


market


risk


(which


measures


the


sensitivity


of


the


firm’s


stock


price


to


market


-wide


movements),


and


specific


risk


(which


measures


the


stock


price


movements


which


are


specific


to the firm, and independent of market movements). According to the CAPM and


APT models, well-diversified investors hold portfolios that have already


eliminated


all


of


a


firm’s


specific


risk,


but


investors


cannot


eliminate


market


risk. The equilibrium market price of each firm’


s shares in the portfolio is


such that expected returns


only


compensate investors


for holding market


risk,


as


embodied


in


a


firm’s


beta.


As


such,


risk


-management


activities


by


the


firm


are


irrelevant


in


the


sense


that


they


are


unable


to


add


value.


These


activities


may reduce total risk, but diversified investors have already done so by


eliminating all of the specific risk. Hence, risk management activities will


not increase the market price of the firm’s shares.




Shapiro and Titman (1998) argue that, since financial instruments are


fairly priced, and compensate investors for market risk only, hedging risk


through financial instruments is, at best, a zero net present value (NPV)


activity.


In


the


worst


scenario,


risk


management


may


actually


be


value


reducing,


since it may be a costly activity in terms of time and resources.



Risk


management


irrelevance


can


be


analysed


as


follows.


Consider


the


value


of the firm as the sum of the discounted value of expected future cashflows.


That is, if the firm is expecting cashflows of X1 in year i, and the firm


discounts at a cost of capital r, then firm value V is given by: V



1


=X



1


/(1+r)


+ X



2


/(1+r)^2+

< p>


(1) The cost of capital (or the investors



required return)


includes an element for market risk. The


firm’s risk management activities


reduce total risk, but this will not affect the market risk. Therefore, the


firm’s beta will be unchanged, and hence the cost of capital


r will remain


the same.



Having demonstrated how risk management may be (at best) an irrelevant


activity,


Sheperd


and


Titman


(1998)


proceed


to


rescue


risk


management


by


showing


that


it


can


have


an


effect


on


firm


value.


They


argue


that


total


risk


does


matter,


through its effects on the cashflows. A high level of total risk may increase


expectations


of


financial


distress,


hence


reducing


the


expected


cashflows,


and


reducing firm value. Risk management aimed at reducing total risk, although


not affecting the discount


rate,


may increase


expected cashflows, which


would


be value increasing.



Furthe


rmore, a firm’s managers have an incentive to engage in risk


management, even if this is not value increasing. A single firm’s financial


distress may not be of much concern for a well-diversified investor. However,


it could be disastrous for the management of that firm, in terms of loss of


employment and reputation. It may be argued that management has a private


discount


rate


which


reflects


total


risk,


and


hence


exceeds


the


social


discount


rate r. Since the firm is valued in the market using r, the management would


have a lower private valuation of the firm than the market. Risk management


could then be viewed as management’s attempts to increase their private


valuation towards the market valuation.



Should we adjust the discount rate?



Shimko (2001) argues that well-diversified investors do not exist.


Therefore,


the


NPV


method


of


investment


appraisal


may


be


flawed,


since


it


uses


a discount rate that only reflects market risk. He proposes an adjustment to


the


NPV


method


in


order


to


take


account


of


total


risk.


His


risk-adjusted


present


value (RPV) method attacks the problem by adjusting the discount rate.



Shimko’s RPV approach is derived as follows.



Consider a one period investment project with present value V



1


at time 0


(this


is


the


amount


that


the


investor


is


prepared


to


pay


at


time


0,


and


is


defined


as cash capital). The time 1 cashflow provided by the project is a normally


distributed


random


variable


with


mean


μ


1


and


standard


deviation


σ


1.


Shimko


assumes that the cashflow is not correlated with any market risk factors. The


risk-free rate is r.



The investor requires a return on his/her cash capital and his/her risk


capital. Risk capital is the maximum amount that the investor might lose on


the


project


over


the


year.


In


order


to


derive


risk


capital,


the


firm


must


define


a “worst case” time 1 cashflow,


W


1


=


μ

1


? is, the worst case cashflow is


z



standard


deviations


below


the


mean.


The


present


value


of


the


worst


case


cashflow


is W



0


=W


1


/ (1+r). Hence, risk capital =V


0

?W


0


.



The expected capital gain over the year is: μ


1


-V=r*V


0


+k*(V


0


-W


0< /p>


) (2)



The left- hand side shows that the expected capital gain is the expected


time 1 value (that is, the mean) minus the initial cash investment. The


right-hand side partitions this expected gain into the return on cash capital


r*V


0


plus the return on risk capital k* (V


0


?W


0


).



Shimko re-arranges (2) to provide the following formulation:



V


0


=


μ


1


/ (1+r)



(k/ (1+r+k))*(z*


σ


1


/ (1+r)) (3)



This suggests that the value of the project equals its NPV value minus a


risk charge that is proportional to the difference between the expected value


and the worst case value.




The project



s cash flows are not correlated




Note that, since it is assumed that the project’s cashflows are not


correlated with the market, the NPV is found by discounting the expected


cashflow at the risk-free rate. Shimko points out that we obtain the NPV


formulation, V


0



1


/ (1+


r


), as a special case when k= 0. Furthermore, as k=



∞ the value of the asset approaches its worst case value


W


0


. Hence, the value


of the asset is affected by total risk, and particularly the value-at- risk.



This approach emphasises that, when there are limitations to portfolio


diversification, investors (and managers) become concerned with total risk.


The RPV method allows us


to


focus on a


crucial element of risk management;


the


value-at-risk.


A


potential


drawback


is


that


the


value


V


0



is


affected


by


different


agents’


private


valuations,


either


through


k,


or


through


the


choice


of


W


0



(since


this choice affects z). Indeed, the author presents numerical examples that


show


that


NPV


valuation


can


be


much


greater


than


the


subjective


RPV


valuation.


Therefore, using


RPV could


have serious problems


for investment appraisal.


It


is possible that the RPV method could lead to incorrect project


acceptance/rejection decisions.



It is better to adjust the cashflows!



In


this


section,


we


provide


an


approach


to


investment


appraisal


based


upon


Shapiro and Titman (1998) rather than Shimko (2001). The goal of investment


appraisal is to identify and accept value-increasing projects. This method


should


reflect


the


market


valuation


of


the


project.


If


we


assume


that


the


CAPM


formulation


is


robust,


and


that


investors


are


only


rewarded


for


holding


market


risk, it is better to adjust the cash-flows rather than the discount rate. In


our analysis, we retain the idea of value-at-risk, specifically relating it


to financial distress.



Consider a one period investment opportunity that requires investment of


l at time 0. The time 1 cashflow X


is normally distributed, with mean μ1 and


standard deviation σ1. Furthermore, if the realised cashflow is le


ss than l,


the firm faces financial distress. This carries a cost of F, where F reflects


disruption to services, loss of reputation, legal costs and so forth. The


expected


cost


of


financial


distress


is


E



(F)


=F


*


Pr


ob{X


<


l}.


In


our


subsequent


worked example, we show that calculation of E



(F) is straightforward.



The cost of capital k


reflects market (not total) risk. The project’s


present


value


equals


the


present


value


of


expected


cashflows


minus


the


present


value of financial distress costs:



V


0


=


μ


1


/ (1+k)



E



(F)/ (1+k) (4)



Note


that


this


is


analogous


to


the


RPV


formulation


(3).


Like


the


RPV


model,


our valuation formula takes account of the value-at-risk. However, we


explicitly


model


this


as


financial


distress,


and


we


introduce


it


in


the


cashflow,


rather than the discount rate.



The NPV formula is:



NPV=-l+ (


μ


1


-E



(F))/ (1+k) (5)



The


firm


takes


the


project


if


NPV



0,


since


this


will


be


value


-increasing.



Like the RPV model, we can incorporate private valuations through the E


(F) term. Let F represent the costs of financial distress to well-diversified


investors,


and


let


Fm


represent


the


costs


of


financial


distress


to


the


firm’s


management.


Due


to


the


arguments


relating


to


well- diversified


investors


versus


non-diversified


managers


set


out


previously,


we


would


expect


Fm


>F.


Management


may be tempted to incorporate the expected value E



(Fm) into the NPV formula


such that:



NPVm=-l*(


μ


1


-E



(F))/ (1+k)



If


NPVm


<


0


<


NPV,


self-interested


management


may


reject


a


value- increasing


project. We do not pursue this avenue in this paper. Instead, we assume that


managers act in the interests of shareholders.




Sufficiently to eliminate financial distress




Risk-management and its effect on firm value



Assume


that


management


can


spend


an


amount


C


on


risk- management


activities.


Furthermore, assume that this activity reduces total risk sufficiently to


eliminate financial distress.


If


the management takes


the project and


carries


out risk-management activities, the NPV will be:



NPV=-l-C+

μ


1


/ (1+k), (7) where the subscript rm signifies NPV after


risk- management.



If


the


management


takes


the


project


and


does


not


carry


out


risk


management


activities, NPV is given by (5).



Note


that


NPVrm


>


NPV


if


E


(F)/


(1


+


k)


>


C.


This


means


that


risk


management


activities


are


worthwhile


if


the


elimination


of


the


present


value


of


financial


distress


costs


exceeds


the


expenditure


required


on


risk


management


activities.



The project acceptance and


risk


management decision


rules are as follows:



Take the project, and risk manage if NPVrm>0, and NPVrm>NPV.


Risk-management activities are value-adding, and the project has a positive


NPV after such activities.


-


-


-


-


-


-


-


-



本文更新与2021-02-10 01:24,由作者提供,不代表本网站立场,转载请注明出处:https://www.bjmy2z.cn/gaokao/625411.html

财务风险管理是一个增值活动吗文献翻译的相关文章